Pages

Showing posts with label World Economics. Show all posts
Showing posts with label World Economics. Show all posts

1941: World Economics

With the official declarations of war between the United States and Japan (Dec. 8, 1941) Germany and Italy (Dec. 11, 1941), the encirclement of the earth by armed conflict was completed; and while most Latin American nations were not actively at war, their situation hardly constitutes an exception to the statement that world economics is now war economics. Since the position of the different countries is discussed in detail elsewhere in this volume (See names of separate nations; also INTERNATIONAL BANKING AND FINANCE) the present article will attempt to give a picture of the salient trends of the world economic situation as a whole, with selective illustration. It must be noted however that one of the effects of the world crisis has been a drastic decline in both the quantity and quality of international information.

INTERNAL WARTIME ECONOMIC CONTROLS

Great Britain.

The experience of different countries with the problem of the price-level in wartime is of more than passing interest. In Britain, as elsewhere, the chief factor making for a rise of prices has been government expenditure. Since such expenditure on disbursement becomes income in private hands, a large proportion of it tends to increase the effective demand for a shrinking supply of consumer goods and commercial materials. If the whole of the war-expenditure could be taken currently from the pocket of the consumer by taxation, the pressure on the price-level would be relieved; a similar result would follow, for the time being, if it were met by voluntary savings taken out of current income. The extent to which these expedients are practicable, especially in a free country, is limited; nor in any case would they afford a complete solution of the problem, since along with a drastic change in the composition of current real income, its total must be vastly enlarged. This expansion may be to some extent brought about by the utilization of hitherto idle, or partially used, resources — in this respect the United States in 1941 was in a fortunate position; but it calls also for additional effort in the internal economy, with additional reward in the form of purchasing power, and for an intensification of demand for certain services and commodities in the international sphere. This expansion of the total production is everywhere financed mainly by the increase of bank loans and advances to the state, resulting in the creation of new credit money, much of which presently engenders an additional demand for, and supply of, currency; and since the accompanying expansion of production is not in the field of those goods and services which are demanded by consumers, upward pressure on the price-level is unavoidable. To offset this kind of pressure, three types of control are in general use: price limitation, rationing and priority-listing of goods, and direct limitations on the monetary amount of consumer purchasing.

Between September 1939 and September 1941 wholesale prices in Britain advanced 57 per cent, cost-of-living index by 28 per cent. By November 1941 the latter figure had risen to 44 per cent. In the early months of the war the rise in basic materials was sharp, due to the depreciation of the pound and the consequently enhanced cost of imports. Since the additional demand for imports supervened on a period of deficits on the trade and services account, the effect was severe; and war conditions did not favor an expansion of exports arising from the depreciation. It may be remarked that the history of the past ten years shows many cases in which such expansion, though theoretically probable, failed to occur.

Also of importance in 1939 were the increases in shipping and insurance costs, which it is one of the objects of blockade to bring about. This situation was eventually met by the government requisitioning British-owned vessels at contract prices; but such a move, while it may control, does not avert rising costs, which continued to mount during 1940. Various types of government underwriting were added to commercial insurance, but the shipping situation remained urgent until American resources came to the rescue.

Basic commodity prices in Britain rose little during 1940, and their cost was largely controlled by bulk purchases made by the Government. The entire New Zealand and Australian wool crop was acquired for the duration of the war and one year after. Much of this supply is in the United States as a British asset. Dried fruit from South Africa, bacon and dairy produce from Canada, copper, zinc and lead from Australia and Canada, the greater part of the Canadian aluminum production, Rhodesian copper, Argentine beef are among the bulk contracts thus secured at fixed prices. None the less, total supplies of consumers' goods have decreased, despite a subsidized extension of agricultural acreage and domestic food production, of which the entire output is now acquired by the Ministry of Food at favorable prices to producers and resold at a loss. By mid-1941 the volume of goods other than food available for sale to consumers had decreased by 50 per cent, according to an official inquiry; and a further diminution was expected as accumulated stocks were used up. On the other hand, the situation of essential food and commodity supplies was better at the close of 1941 than for two years previous, thanks largely to American aid.

The controls established in Britain may be summarized as follows: First, the Limitation of Supplies orders restrict the amounts of non-food commodities that may be released by wholesalers to retailers to a stated proportion (by money-value) of certain defined base-periods. The original base-period, six months ending Nov. 30, 1939, is now generally superseded by a similar period ending May 31, 1940; and the quotas run from 50 to 25 per cent. Sales of certain goods on the domestic market, including automobiles, wooden furniture and silk stockings, are prohibited altogether. In the case of textiles the Limitation of Supplies system is reinforced or modified by the system of ration cards for clothing.

Second, the rationing system has been steadily extended and improved. Tea, condensed milk, canned meat and fish, and eggs were added to the list of rationed foods in 1941, but the improving situation permitted enlargements of the allowances of cheese, sugar and fats in the latter half of the year. It was expected that food supplies from the United States, which constituted 5 to 6 per cent of the total in October, could be increased to as much as 25 per cent. The rationing system was increasingly supplemented during 1941 by the opening of canteens and restaurants under Government control at which workers in heavy industry could obtain extra allowances of meat and certain other foods. The feeding of school children also was considerably extended.

A third kind of control was represented in the type of rationing used, for example, in regard to meat, based not on quantity of commodity but on allowable money expenditure. This may be classed with the compulsory deferred savings feature of the last budget (see also INTERNATIONAL BANKING AND FINANCE) as a direct restriction of consumer spending. However, the limitations to such restriction are serious. In a free country it is exceedingly difficult to persuade workers to accept a curtailment of their standard of living at the precise time when their services are most valuable and their labor hardest. The British trade unions have not favored schemes to 'freeze' wages at levels which would have this effect. The argument that wages should be kept level with the cost-of-living index is hard to resist — though available statistics indicate that both wage-rates and weekly earnings have lagged some 10 points behind it. Yet since wages reappear as costs of production an 'inflationary spiral' may easily develop in so far as the economy is left free to settle its own prices. Increasing measures of both rationing and price control are therefore to be expected. Among basic price control measures added in 1941 should be mentioned the Government leasing of all British railroads for a fixed rental of £43,000,000 annually, to continue one year after war.

Germany.

In Germany, the nature and direction of the social system facilitated the imposition of stricter and more systematic controls at a much earlier date. Modern war demands a reorganization of the entire economic life of a community. No other states had advanced so far in this direction as Germany since 1933 and Japan since 1935. It is probable that in these cases alone had the advancement, or maintenance, of the civilian standard of living been consistently put second to the organization of the collective striking power. Particularly in respect of the control of profits and savings, the investment of new capital, the integration and location of heavy industry, and the stimulation of directed research, these powers presented a striking contrast to those which professed a desperate faith in the possibility of peace. Recent evidence suggests that the Russian government, in the above-named respects, displayed more foresight than was credited to it at the time.

The key to German policy of the past seven years is the intention to provide for an expanding economy, with its industrial center in western Europe, along lines which a land-power could control. This has involved carefully planned efforts, backed by various degrees of economic and military force, to achieve an expanding integration comparable with that which naval powers have been able to achieve in respect of overseas territories. Certain aspects of the expansion will be treated below; a necessary preliminary to the national effort required was an inventory of the estimated needs and resources for several years ahead, coupled with a systematic effort to produce or accumulate them within the home territory. Some phases of this effort are well known: for example, the large-scale production of synthetic rubber, which may be put at from 75,000 to 100,000 tons yearly (as compared with 15,000 tons in the United States for 1941) or about the normal pre-war consumption of greater Germany. The development of synthetic fuel-oils, fibres and plastics is also a familiar story. Such efforts at increased self-sufficiency were coupled, since 1934, with the piling-up of food and commodity reserves. Naturally, no statistics are available, but it is reliably reported that the stocks of cereals and fats were intended to last well into 1942 at the planned minimum rates of consumption.

What these rates were may be gauged from the German ration-system. This system which was put into effect immediately on the outbreak of war, had undergone remarkably little change up to November 1941; the only alterations of importance reported during that year (others may have taken place) were cuts of 25 per cent in the meat allowance, and 40 per cent in the clothing ration — this latter reflecting a decline in the stocks of cotton and wool, coupled with a shortage of labor and an increase in the army demand; the situation called for an emergency clothing collection for the troops in December 1941. In July 1941, as reported by the U.S. Department of Agriculture, normal consumers were entitled weekly to 4.96 pounds of bread or flour equivalent, .331 lb. of other farinaceous foods, .882 lb. of meat and meat products, .592 lb. of fats, .496 lb. of sugar, .331 lb. of marmalade (or .248 lb. additional sugar), .021 lb. artificial honey, .138 lb. of cheese, .069 lb. of curds. Milk was reserved entirely for children, and extra food allowances were available to heavy workers and special categories. As in the case of Britain, official statements testified that general health showed no deterioration. A feature of the systems in both countries was the artificial enrichment of the vitamin contents of basic foods. In both cases it must be borne in mind that the mere provision of a ration-card is no guarantee of the availability of the amount stated.

German measures of price-control date from long before the war. A general 'freezing' order, effective Nov. 26, 1936, forbade the increase of prices above the figures of Oct. 16, 1936; and this basis was maintained as the determining factor throughout 1940. In consequence, both the wholesale and cost-of-living indices for December 1940 showed little rise above their pre-war levels. On the basis of 1913 = 100, wholesale prices stood at 107.1 in August 1939 and 110.9 in December 1940; the cost-of-living index at 127.3 and 130.8. At the beginning of the war the original basis was supplemented by an elaborate system of controls, designed on the one hand to keep down costs and selling prices for public contracts, on the other, to curtail consumer buying by holding prices at pre-war levels. This entailed control of profit-margins, especially of differential gains arising from unequal costs of producing price-fixed articles. In general, the policy has been to prevent such gains being passed into purchasing power either as wage advances or additional dividends. Wage-rates were 'frozen' concurrently with prices, and the profits policy aims, roughly speaking, at recapturing all profits above 6 per cent; war profits being taken in their entirety. This policy, difficult of complete execution as are all such efforts, has not prevented a boom in German industrial stocks during 1941.

The price policy was further elaborated at the beginning of 1941 in the direction of cost-control; the intention being to place on producers the onus of justifying to the price-controllers all increases above the 1936 base. The same general principle of price-freezing, backed by systematic and minute regulations for each industry, has been applied to all industrial areas under German hegemony: Norway, Finland, Holland, France, Belgium, Slovakia, Hungary, Croatia all find their 'free' enterprise controlled and coordinated with as much efficiency as the social and political state of affairs permits.

The direct restriction of consumer purchasing power has also been carried much farther in Germany than elsewhere. To the fixing of wages and recapture of profits, which were well-established features of the German economy, the war added not only more taxes, but more deductions at the source. In the first winter of the war wages were subject to eight regular deductions: wages tax, war surcharge, civic tax, defense tax (on men not conscripted), three social insurance payments, dues to the Labor Front and contribution to the 'winter help.' These have since been consolidated and simplified, but the principle of deferred wages (called 'iron savings') has been introduced as in Britain. In Germany it takes the form of a so-called voluntary undertaking by the wage-earner to forego a part of his wage, which is thenceforward automatically withheld and placed in a special savings account that is locked until a year after the war; such sum being deductible from the wage for taxing purposes. A somewhat similar scheme is available to employers for depreciation funds or reserves.

United States.

Details of the internal economy of the United States are given elsewhere in this volume; but certain of its aspects may here be noted for comparative purposes. The war emergency supervened on many years of deficit financing, of which war preparation formed only a partial objective. The extremely high levels of bank deposits, note circulation and bank reserves reached in 1941 contained a high inflation potential; but for the time being the exceptional demand for consumers' goods was met out of accumulated inventories, and by the utilization of unused capacity and idle resources. By the end of the year this recourse had reached its limit in several directions, notably steel and other metals, and priority ratings were proving an effective means of rationing raw materials to industry and thereby curtailing civilian supply. Secondly, while no general price-stop was contemplated, control of prices was rapidly extended in the closing months of 1941. By mid-January 1942 the Office of Price Administration had made effective more than 60 'price ceilings' and brought another 100 commodities under informal control. These limitations covered nearly one-third of the national sales volume exclusive of retail selling. In so far, however, as the policy of price control permeated the field of consumer goods, recourse to rationing appeared probable, since without it a very inequitable distribution would result; a sudden and severe beginning was made in respect of automobile tires in January 1942.

Serious difficulties lay ahead, however. Wage-rates and earnings showed an almost unchecked advance, with the possibility of an inflationary cost spiral; the prospect of continued competitive bidding for labor by expanding war industry coupled with further inroads on the supply arising from the requirements of an expanding army strengthened the labor opposition to anything in the nature of a 'ceiling' on wages. The political strength of agricultural interests seeking to enlarge the farmers' share of national income constituted a further obstacle to effective price control. And while the eventual contraction of consumer purchasing power via taxes promised to be considerable, much might happen before such direct restriction became fully effective.

EXTERNAL WARTIME ECONOMICS

To a far greater extent than in the previous case, the present World War has been prepared for, and fought on, the economic front. The German effort to secure the economic hegemony of Central and Southeastern Europe has proceeded systematically since 1934; the Japanese bid for dominance in Northern East Asia has been in progress for over ten years; and in both cases the ultimate resort to arms was envisaged as a probable consummation of the policy of expansion. Centrally controlled regional economies with a maximum degree of self-sufficiency and a powerful bargaining position in respect of the open areas would appear to be the objectives; and such aims made inevitable a collision with both the politico-economic entities lying in the path of expansion and the external affiliations of France, Britain and America.

German Plan of Economic Integration.

The German plan of economic integration for the European area has made rapid headway since the fall of France, along lines fairly familiar to students of German methods. These may be briefly summarized as follows.

(1) While, in general, subjugated areas have been left with their local currencies, and even with considerable gold reserves, the rates of exchange with the reichsmark have been uniformly dictated at ratios extremely favorable to Berlin. Thus German forces in France have been enabled to conduct a disguised appropriation of French goods and properties: German buying agents in the Danube valley have been able to offer high prices for produce in local currency out of resources inflated by an arbitrary translation of the mark values of goods and credits supplied by Germany.

(2) The absence or closing of other markets has enabled Germany in large measure to dictate the economic activity of the subjugated areas; and the revised pattern of European integration controlled from Berlin has naturally erased such economic independence as was possessed by the former political units. Thus, for example, Alsatian agriculture is to be expanded, with enlarged planting of sugar-beet, oilseeds and tobacco and reduced acreage of hops; French winter wheat acreage has been enlarged and soybean cultivation stimulated; livestock production in Denmark and Holland is being curtailed because of the dependence on imported feeds, while its expansion is demanded in eastern and southeastern Europe where local fodder can be made sufficient. A large increase in the planting of olives and oilseeds was laid down for France, and an enlargement of the acreage under wheat and root crops for Belgium. In Poland large-scale agriculture was directly organized by Germans, aimed at an increase of from 50 to 100 per cent in the cereal-yield per acre. It may be suggested that the Italian economic design for an industrial system fed by overseas raw materials and fuel would need considerable revision to fit the Berlin plans. These demanded, among other things, increased cotton planting in southern Europe, Italy included. While much of the foregoing is undoubtedly in the blue-print stage, its execution is accelerated by certain factors, among which these may be mentioned: the control of prices exerted everywhere by German officials; the destitution consequent on German requisitioning, and on the shortage of agricultural labor; the German control of agricultural equipment and stock; and the transfer of masses of people from one area to another, including prisoners of war, Jews, Poles, Slovaks and Croats.

(3) The economic integration of the subjugated areas has been accelerated by a planned unification of the European transport system. Considerable progress in this direction was made since 1936 by means of concessions for railroad and canal construction, and Danubian and Black Sea port facilities. The process was accelerated after the annexation of Austria, especially in central European road construction. War conditions have brought a rigid restriction of civilian travel, reorganization of German traction organizations, concentration of production to eliminate bulk haulage, and systematic control of priorities by both the army command and regional commissars. On the other hand, the elimination of sea transport and the shortage of fuel have imposed a critical strain on all transport facilities — to say nothing of sabotage. It may be noted that a similar development and unification of road, rail and water transport is proceeding, under Anglo-American control, in the region between the Persian Gulf and the Caucasus.

(4) The expansion of German industrial control has been the most striking feature of the European economic front. The methods employed have been, broadly speaking, as follows. First, the placing of large orders dictated by the Wehrwirtschaft, experts of the German High Command, to take the place of contracts cancelled or eliminated by the subjugation of the local economies and the German control of raw materials. In most cases such orders offer the only alternative to wholesale unemployment. Prices, wages and profit-margins are all regulated. Second, there has been a rapid expansion of German bank control. The leading Viennese banks have been absorbed, with their trading and industrial connections in Southeastern Europe; the two leading banks in Slovakia were acquired; the five leading Rumanian banks have admitted German participation, and German banks hold a majority control of the Yugoslav Banking Union; in Poland, Alsace-Lorraine and Luxemburg German banks have opened branches; in both Northwestern Europe and the Balkans German-owned or controlled subsidiaries have facilitated financial penetration. The control of all foreign-exchange dealings, and the tying of local currencies to the mark, have been effective instruments of control by means of capital or loan participation. Third, the leading German concerns, under state direction, have been active in reorganizing or incorporating enterprises in occupied territory; especially the Reichswerke H. Goering A.G. (of which Skoda is now a subsidiary), the Kontinentale Oel A.G., and the I. G. Farbenindustrie. This has been done mainly by large issues of new share capital, very little of which has been offered publicly. Fourth, the cartel system, with various modifications, has been so widely extended as to make it the main instrument of German hegemony. German dominance in the International Steel and other cartels has been used to bring production and marketing policies into line. Franco-German collaboration was rapidly advanced in 1941 by this means, as for example in the Franco-German-Italian automobile agreement, and the combination of twenty French textile concerns with certain Finnish and Norwegian enterprises in a vastly enlarged cellulose syndicate. A European re-insurance cartel has also been organized.

While the stability and duration of all these arrangements may well be questioned, they obviously have implications which cannot be ignored in regard to the perennial conflict between the political and the economic bases of European reconstruction; the more so as in many cases — especially that of Poland — they mask a struggle for control between German, French, American and British capital.

Japanese Economic Penetration.

In the Far East the Japanese plan for grossraumwirtschaft, culminating in war on the United States, appeared in 1941 still to be producing more hardship than benefits. Rationing, which had been drastic since 1937, was further curtailed by a shortage of rice in the spring of 1941 — a commodity in which Japan is usually self-supporting. The German war on Russia closed the land-route for Japanese exports to the west; and only the tolerance of Britain and America maintained the supply of essential raw materials to Japanese industry and armament. The freezing of Japanese assets by the democracies in July had a double effect. So far as capital value was concerned, the Japanese retaliation affected a much greater total of Anglo-American properties than that of Japanese assets abroad; but the stoppage of trade was disastrous to Japan, whose exports to the democracies were of far greater relative importance than were theirs to Japan. Japanese merchants were left with inventories of goods whose sale in the home market, even if possible, was forbidden by war restrictions on consumption. Since the Dutch followed suit, a rapid expansion into new territories was almost an economic necessity, and had undoubtedly been long prepared for.

So far as meagre information indicates, the principal Japanese effort at consolidation in northern East Asia has taken the form of railroad-building. Japanese industries have in at least some cases been moved into Manchukuo, mining has been developed, and soybean cultivation still further extended. The economic régime, however, would appear to be insecure, inasmuch as the railroads are still subject to guerilla attack. Japanese gains in Indo-China and Thailand, if held, are of substantial economic importance; they include a possible 1,000,000 tons of anthracite per year from the former, together with rice, fish, tea, zinc, tin, wolfram, rubber and other commodities. Details are lacking as to the methods of exploitation.

In China, Japanese economic control in 1941 appeared to go little farther than the direct military occupation; while Free China, with its currency and imports sustained by British and American advances, made remarkable headway in developing its own resources. The extension of government banking is elsewhere alluded to (See INTERNATIONAL BANKING AND FINANCE). The economic program of the government called for extension of the munitions industries, development of new steel plants, an improvement and extension of tin mining, and further erection of power plants, textile mills and machine shops. The import of industrial machinery has exceeded 30,000 tons in four years. The most immediate task was that of road-building to allow a more rapid development of truck traffic; but considerable railroad mileage was also undertaken in 1941, some of it paralleling the Burma road.

American Economic Influence.

As in the domestic economy of nearly all nations, the international economic relations of the entire world were completely dominated by war and war policies in 1941. While the United States did not participate as an active belligerent until December, its economic policies gave practical and cumulative expression to the sympathies of its people throughout, and even before, the period of hostilities. Control of foreign trade from this point of view was much more thoroughly applied than in the previous war; as for example, in the 'moral embargo' laid upon the export of airplanes, parts and aviation gas to Russia on Dec. 2, 1939, and maintained during the period of hostilities with Finland until Jan. 21, 1941. Positive economic assistance to certain nations before the passage of the Lend-Lease Act in March 1941 was likewise guided by broad considerations of foreign policy; for example, a year-end statement by Mr. James A. Farrell, chairman of the National Foreign Trade Council, explained that loans and credits extended to Latin-American countries should be regarded as 'primarily of a political character and should not be confounded with investments designed to increase our trade.' The continued support given through the Reconstruction Finance Corporation to the government and people of Free China may be taken to reflect more than purely economic motives, as may also, perhaps, the continuance of gold and silver purchasing from nations most of whom happen to be actual or potential allies of the United States.

The heavy purchases of reserve supplies from overseas by agencies of the American government strongly influenced both the composition and direction of foreign trade; and the continuance of export licensing under the National Defense Act of July 1940 provided an effective means of aligning commercial activity with national requirements. Still further pressure was applied by the freezing of all assets of Germany, Italy and all invaded or occupied countries on June 14. 1941, followed by the closing of their consulates and by retaliatory measures on the part of the nations affected. With this action the closing of the European market was virtually completed, but the loss of exports to the continent was almost entirely compensated by the gain in exports to Great Britain, due at first to British purchases and after March to the operation of the Lend-Lease Act. For the first nine months of 1941 total exports to Northwestern and Central Europe amounted to $1,056,087,274 as against $1,096,159,621 in 1940; yet every country in the list showed a heavy drop except Iceland, whose receipts of American goods and equipment went up from $1,500,000 to over $4,000,000, and the United Kingdom, which received $1,024,212,180 of American exports in 1941 as compared with $698,151,708 the year before. The corresponding figure for the whole of 1939 was $505,226,000.

Among other measures of economic war must be mentioned the 'blacklisting' of firms, agencies and individuals of whatever nationality or location, accused or suspected of doing business with enemy states or their nationals; the effect of the blacklist is to prohibit all Americans from commercial or financial intercourse with such concerns, thereby freezing their American assets. The policy was started on July 17, 1941, when the State Department ostracized 1,800 German and Italian firms and individuals in Latin America. Some 3,000 Japanese firms and individuals were subsequently added. On Jan. 14, 1942, the policy was extended to Europe, in close cooperation with Great Britain. The new list included 506 firms or individuals doing business in Portugal, 166 in Portuguese possessions, 369 in Spain. 52 in Spanish possessions, 82 in Sweden, 196 in Turkey, and more than 400 in Switzerland. The list includes all types and sizes of concerns, and a variety of commodities ranging from shoes and films to aluminum and insurance.

So far as Latin America was concerned, very considerable dislocation of business resulted; but it was authoritatively stated at the close of 1941 that total exports to that continent had not been diminished. The figures bear this out. Total exports for September 1940 were $25,072,223; for September 1941, $48,561,109. Over nine months the totals were $337,537,964 for 1940, and $330,692,917 for 1941; Venezuela, the Argentine and Paraguay showed declines.

While no exact proportion can be cited, it is safe to say that nearly the whole of this trade falls under the direct control, positive or negative, of the American Government. The licensing of exports (with extended licensing of imports a probable sequel), the huge American purchases, the customary State Department supervision of private loans, the large official loans and investments of government agencies, the elimination of enemy enterprise, the American state maritime insurance, the scarcity and control of shipping, the gold and silver purchase policies and the latent executive power over the value of the American dollar, all point in the direction of a more than transitory integration of the economic life of the western hemisphere; a tendency which the grossraum economy of the Axis at present tends to reinforce. On the other hand, Mr. Farrell, in the statement above cited, claims that such measures 'should not lead us to the mistaken conclusion that hemispheric self-containment is either practical or desirable. What is natural in wartime stimulation of trade with our southern neighbors ought to be retained after the war, but we should shun the delusion that either Latin America or ourselves would benefit by any artificial efforts on our part to supplant Europe in future trade with that area. Recovery by Latin America of its vital stake in European markets must in the end prove advantageous to us through our multilateral transactions, on which we so largely depend in normal times.' In export circles, however, considerable speculation arose during the latter part of 1941 as to how feasible, or extensive, would be any possible return to privately directed international enterprise. Obligations arising out of American government advances, as well as the settlements for aid and supplies extended under the Lend-Lease Act, would continue to place considerable directive power in government hands; an extension of the international cartel system would ultimately tend in the same direction; and the all-important question of exchange and currency stabilization would demand direct international negotiation.

United States economic relations with Central America were without question permanently tightened during 1941; particularly with Mexico, 65 per cent of whose foreign trade came northward in consequence of the war. The preliminary economic agreement of December 1941, and the detailed arrangements to follow, presage a degree of integration that both geography and commonsense demand. Trade with Canada continued to increase, exports (nine months) rising from $510,978,483 to $675,306,240 in 1941, and imports received from $301,045,693 to $391,305,623. Notwithstanding that a very high proportion of this trade is strictly on war account, a permanent strengthening of the economic bonds of the Northern continent would appear inevitable. See also articles on BUSINESS; INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCES; WORLD WAR II.

1940: World Economics

Shifts to War Economies.

During 1940 the fundamental adjustment of world economic conditions to a war basis continued. In the early months of the year there were general declines in production and prices from the speculative position reached in the closing months of last year. Later, in most countries war production got under way in real earnest and signs of inflation multiplied.

In Great Britain and the British Empire there was a complete mobilization of resources for war purposes and the greater portion of the national income was diverted to this end. Imports to Great Britain were heavy considering the constant attacks on shipping. Financial conditions at home were comparatively easy though price rises were substantial. The foreign exchange position of the currency was protected. Continental Europe was almost completely cut off from the outside world by the British Blockade after the fall of France in June. Germany proceeded to the consolidation of the production of these countries for war purposes and with plans for their future position in Europe. Germany's financial position remained relatively stable at home but in the occupied countries and those remaining neutral inflation became increasingly a menace. The United States, after the downfall of France, proceeded to press production of defense goods for itself and war materials for Britain. By the end of the year the increases in credit which accompanied this program began to show their effects on prices. In South America the breakdown of normal trade relations with Europe produced severe repercussions. Increased trade with Great Britain and with the United States in certain lines helped to fill the gap. The United States made further loans to several countries to finance trade and to stabilize currencies, and a convention providing for the Inter-American Bank was drafted. In the Orient, Japanese production was at lower levels than in 1939. During the first half year the export surplus continued but in the second half year foreign trade was sharply curtailed and imports exceeded exports. Foreign exchange remained steady, however. In China, trade became difficult but the value of imports increased rapidly compared with exports. Inflation at home was rapid but the depreciation in foreign exchange value of the currency was mitigated by loans from the United States. As the year closed it was abundantly evident that in spite of the improvement of techniques of management, this war, like that of 1914, would be accompanied by financial disturbances as well as the direct privations of the war itself.

Great Britain and the British Empire.

The main structure for the regulation of economic life in Great Britain during the war was laid down in 1939. In 1940 its scope widened and its enforcement was more strict. As the countries of the continent fell into enemy hands, trade became more restricted and the tonnage of vessels available for foreign trade shrank as sinkings multiplied. The intensification of bombing tended to curtail domestic production and to disrupt transportation. Under these circumstances government control had to be strengthened. The primary object was to produce all possible material for the war while maintaining a minimum standard of living for the civilian population. Otherwise, as great liberty as possible was given to the citizens, much more than was the case in Germany.

Production continued to be shifted from consumers' goods to war materials. Although indexes of production were no longer published evidence of the magnitude of the shift is given by the fact that retail stores were allowed, by the end of the year, to stock only 25 per cent as much of unessential goods as in 1939. Rationing of food supplies was extended little by little. Even by the end of the year, however, these restrictions applied to raw food purchased, not to purchases at restaurants. Such a system of rationing was much less stringent than the German, but led to criticisms of the government's policies. The poor do not purchase extensively at restaurants so the system allowed the rich to escape from the restrictions which the poor had to bear. Rationing, moreover, was applied only to the more essential and scarce foods. Local producers naturally escaped the restrictions as much as possible. Onions, for instance, which were restricted, ceased to be sold in London markets while sales of pickled onions, on which there were no restrictions, increased in volume. Again this situation brought criticisms. At the end of the year the system of rations was being extended, including a lessening of the amount of meat available for each individual.

Though the problems of civilian rationing were troublesome, difficulties in primary production were intense in many fields. Coal mines on the coast were practically abandoned while those in the interior flourished. Transportation facilities had to be conserved so that demand could not be spread. A similar situation developed in textiles. Plans were developed for providing a distribution of the proceeds of the industry to all companies so that those unfavorably situated because of the government planning should not be forced into bankruptcy. This lack of uniform distribution of orders, however, made necessary some unemployment. In mid-summer the number of registered unemployed amounted to some 750,000 and increased to 835,000 by October. Next summer the plans for production will call for another million workers while the Army and Navy expect to absorb another million. There will be, therefore, a shortage of men.

The destruction of property by bombing became another crucial problem. At first, only the poor were compensated and then only for the loss of buildings, not of personal property such as tools. Later, an insurance plan was inaugurated whereby everyone contributed and everyone was protected at least for a minimum. Nevertheless, bombing came to be a serious threat to productive activity not only because of loss of plant but because of loss of time during air raid alarms. Workers were urged to stay at their posts even after the alarms were given.

Trade with outside countries was, of course, dependent on the tonnage of vessels which could be convoyed into British ports and given dockage. Bombing seriously interfered with trade by the destruction not only of vessels but also of docks. However, in the first ten months of the year imports were higher in value than during 1939. Part of the increase must be ascribed to the change in prices. In November, however, imports declined to £73,000,000 compared with £85,000,000 in the preceding month and £83,000,000 in November 1939. The export trade was sustained because of the need for foreign exchange but not at the levels of the previous year. For the first eleven months of 1940 the import surplus amounted to £617,000,000 compared to £359,000,000 in the same period of 1939.

The diversion of so much productive activity to war needs naturally had its financial repercussions. Fifty per cent of the total national income was absorbed in war expenditures and 60 per cent in government as a whole. Part of these funds were raised by taxation. The basic rate for the income tax was increased to 42.5 per cent, the highest in its history. Sales taxes, especially on luxuries, were imposed and the excess profits tax reached 100 per cent in many cases. All businesses had to pay a National Contribution tax. As a result of these taxes, revenues will cover $5,440,000,000 of the expenditures for the fiscal year ending March 1941, leaving a deficit of $8,424,000,000.

Funds to meet the deficit were raised in part by long term bond issues. Some of these bonds yielded 2½ per cent, others 3 per cent. A special issue with attractive provisions for small borrowers carried 3.17 per cent. Further funds were obtained by taking over savings deposits directly from the banks. The government paid the banks 1½ per cent interest for the use of these funds for a year. Other funds were obtained at short term by the sale of Treasury bills. Rates on these bills declined during the year and were only 1.03 per cent in September.

The resources of the banking system were still adequate to meet the demands upon it. At the commercial banks customers' loans declined enough to make up for the increased holdings of Treasury bills. Deposits increased moderately from £2,278,000,000 in September 1939 to £2,597,000,000 in September 1940. Interest rates declined for commercial loans in the open market. At the Bank of England discounts were at low levels and holdings of securities increased but little. Note issues did expand; they were £592,000,000 in October 1940 compared to £511,000,000 in August 1939 before the outbreak of the war.

Although the changes in banking statistics did not indicate any great inflationary tendencies, prices in Great Britain rose substantially during the first year of the war. The Economists' wholesale price index (1929 = 100) rose from 75 in August 1939 to 107 in October 1940, the cost of living index increased from 95 to 117 in the same period. Price regulation had been provided under the acts of August 1939, but provision was made for changes due to cost of production. Rises in wages led to rises in costs; so did rises in railway rates. The cost-price spiral definitely appeared.

In spite of the rising prices, control of the foreign exchange market was increasingly effective. At first the pound sterling had been unpegged and allowed to find a new level. In March the new official rate was established at $4.035. To maintain this rate the stabilization fund from time to time called in from citizens their holdings of specified lists of securities compensating them with British government bonds. The sale of these securities became an important factor in the New York market when the proceeds were held. The free market for Sterling was gradually restricted. A method of evading the laws prohibiting the withdrawal of capital had been to have foreign subsidiaries of British corporations withdraw funds from the parent company. This practice was finally forbidden in the fall. At the same time, Great Britain entered into agreements with the United States and other American countries providing for clearing arrangements and even, finally, for 'blocked' sterling. As a result the free rate came to coincide practically with the official rate.

In its mobilization of resources, Great Britain attempted to include the whole Empire. In the fall, a conference was held at Delhi to provide a coordinated plan. Production was planned in such a way as to relieve Great Britain of the necessity of sending goods, thus freeing more ships. Such plans, including as they did the building of new factories, were of a long range nature. They will press the industrialization of the Eastern Empire. Not only was production planned but so also was the army and navy necessary for the protection of India and Australia and New Zealand. Thus the burden of defense was shifted from England. The amount of funds for which the Empire could be called upon was also considered. Australia and New Zealand were thought to be in a position to make sacrifices equal to those of Great Britain herself, that is of some 50 per cent of their national income. Their population is not large, however, and thus the contribution would be relatively small. India, with its large population, lives so close to the minimum standard of living that it has little surplus to contribute.

Continental Europe.

On the continent of Europe, the breakdown of France had the most serious economic consequences. In the early months of the year, the course of events had been similar to those in Great Britain. Government regulation of the economic life of the nation had been even more strict, perhaps. Taxes were very heavy. The hours of labor were increased for ordinary businesses and in defense industries could be 72. Wages were fixed at ordinary rates for overtime. All of this was in marked contrast to the conditions of but a few years ago when the Popular Front was in power and very different from conditions in 1914. Price fixing was strict. Of the effectiveness of these controls little evidence is available. Price and production indexes were discontinued. Bank statistics suggest that mild inflation was in progress. Note circulation of the Bank of France increased continuously though gradually. Discounts and deposits of the commercial banks followed a similar course. The value of the franc in the foreign exchange market sagged, reaching 1.85 cents in May. All of the changes were accelerated just before the capitulation came, and with it came a complete disruption of economic life when France was divided into the occupied and unoccupied territories.

In Germany itself, meantime, the pace of financial deterioration of last year continued but was not accelerated appreciably. Note circulation of the Reichsbank which had been 8,989,000,000 reichsmarks before the war rose to 12,937,000,000 of reichsmarks on Oct. 31, 1940. Holdings of Treasury bills by the Reichsbank increased in similar proportion. The index of whole-sale prices rose from 107 (1913 = 100) in October 1939 to 111 in October 1940. Retail prices increased from 122 (1913-14 = 100) in October 1939 to 133 in August 1940. As explained above, rationing in Germany was much more complete and effective than in Great Britain. No data on production or trade is available. Labor shortages were reported and the periods of forced labor in the labor camps was increased. Bombing took its toll on production in Germany, also, but there is no way of discovering how seriously.

As Germany occupied one country after another in western Europe, the financial and productive activities of these countries had to be consolidated with those of the Reich. In each case the plan appears to have been to draw as much in raw materials from these countries as was possible. Manufacturing was not extensively encouraged even for war purposes. In northern France, as the armies retreated the factories were dismantled and machinery was carried behind the lines. Later when this equipment fell into German hands the factories were not reopened. Coal mines in the north were reopened, however, and served to supply German needs. In the reconstructed Europe the evidence seems to point to the concentration of industrial activity in Germany, while other countries are reduced to a dependent position of suppliers of materials. This plan applies to Poland, Norway, Belgium and Holland as well as France.

In each of these countries certain similarities of tactics appeared. From most of them a labor force was moved into Germany to help with the harvest and with other work when there was a shortage of labor. One hundred thousand Dutch were moved in this manner in October, and earlier there were similar transfers from Norway and from Poland. Besides, there were transplantings of whole populations where such a movement seemed desirable, from Lorraine to unoccupied France for instance, when the number of unemployed in Lorraine became too great. Such movements tended to disrupt the labor force at home and to break up national spirit.

Another feature of the occupation was the heavy purchases of products from each country. In 1914 products were simply taken. This time the arrangements were more elaborate. The Germans bought such goods as they wished at prevailing prices in the domestic currency. This process served to allay the antagonism of the population. The funds used in payment were required to be furnished by the Central Bank of the country, which in turn issued bank notes. The German Government then reimbursed the Central Bank with marks or mark assets. But at the same time they charged the country for the expenses of occupation sums sufficient to cover all these assets so that they had to be transferred to Germany again. In fact, the sums were so large that for France alone they exceeded the reparation payments of the last war at their maximum. Although the process was sufficiently complicated so that the ordinary person in those countries failed to grasp its significance, the ultimate result was that Germany acquired goods from the conquered territories while those territories experienced shortages of goods. These shortages were aggravated by the fact that during the acute stages of conflict and for many months afterwards production was severely reduced. Men were called into the army, factories were dismantled or destroyed, transportation broke down. The British blockade cut off the usual sources of materials and closed the customary markets. Crops were destroyed or remained unharvested in the fields. Thus when materials were scarce, the new demands were disastrous. Prices, in the absence of price fixing, rose quickly. In Denmark, for instance, the wholesale price index (1929 = 100) rose from 103 in September 1939 to 169 in October 1940. By winter a serious shortage of food threatened in many places.

Such were the effects of direct invasion. Other countries on the continent were little better off. Italy was already depleted by the Ethiopian war when this war began. Official data on conditions is lacking as in so many other countries. Unofficial sources reported that all imports of coffee, meats, rubber and jute had ceased while imports of oils, fats, cereals, raw cotton, wool and hides had dropped to a small fraction of their former levels. Food prices, already high in 1939, rose 33 per cent after the war began. The rationing of food was very strict and five meatless days a week were required.

Neutral Countries.

In neutral countries declining trade and rising prices were the rule. In Sweden the production index (1929 = 100) dropped from 158 in August 1939 to 133 in August 1940, imports declined from 217,000,000 krone to 123,000,000 krone and exports from 184,000,000 krone to 97,000,000 krone. Meantime, wholesale prices rose from 111 (1935 = 100) in September 1939 to 146 in October 1936. For Switzerland, the situation was similar. Imports and exports declined rapidly and the wholesale price index (1929 = 100) rose from 83 in September 1939 to 108 in September 1940. Both these countries were practically compelled to carry on trade with Germany. Such trading was done under clearing arrangements. In October, a new agreement was negotiated between Switzerland and Germany as the result of which Swiss balances accumulated in Berlin and could not be removed. In a similar way all trade between occupied countries was cleared through Berlin and led to accumulations of credits there. Thus Germany was able to make use of these balances for financing war production while the countries that owned them suffered shortages of goods and, in most cases, inflation.

United States.

In the United States, the transition to production on a war basis came more slowly than was anticipated at first. At the outbreak of war prices of strategic commodities had increased spectacularly. The Bureau of Labor Statistics index of wholesale prices rose 5 per cent in a month and the Annalist's Sensitive price index by 33 per cent. This rapid rise in prices came from a speculative demand for commodities. It was followed by increased production in anticipation of war needs. At its high point in December, the Federal Reserve Board index of industrial production (1935-39 average = 100) was 126. But the war demands did not develop as expected and prices and productive activity declined again in the early months of 1940. The index for production was only 111 in April. The production of durable goods declined even more; the index for December had been 140 but was 113 in April. The wholesale price index meantime dropped from 79.4 (1926 = 100, Bureau of Labor Statistics) to 78.6 in April and continued to decline until it reached 77.4 in August.

When the war became more intense and the threat to American security grew the demand for war materials materialized and with it came the beginnings of an industrial boom. The index of production in general increased slowly at first and then rapidly until it was 128 in October, while that for durable goods reached 151 at the same time. With this increase in production went the normal accompaniments of a boom. The index of employment (1923-25 = 100) rose from 100 in June to 108 in October and that for payrolls from 98 to 114. The wholesale price index increased also under the combined stimulus of war demands and increased payrolls until it was 79.8 in the first week of December. Certain products, notably lumber, increased in price by as much as 20 per cent during the fall.

The increases in prices which occurred in the fall of 1940 were a much more serious matter than those that occurred in 1939. In 1940 price increases came from the increase in demand for goods for the real needs of the defense program and of consumers, those of 1939 from a demand for goods to hold in stock. The demand of 1939 was, therefore, temporary, that of 1940 was a continuing one. It was a serious matter because inflation has always accompanied wars in the past and the banking system of the United States was in a condition to provide the basis of inflation without serious check.

The extreme liquidity of the banking system was a direct result of the heavy imports of gold to this country at a time when the demands of business were not great. The imports in 1939 had seemed very large but those of 1940 were even larger. By the end of the year the United States held 80 per cent of the total gold supply of the world and amounted to $21,755,000,000. This gold supply allowed a reserve of 90 per cent against the liabilities of the Federal Reserve System, a figure more than double the legal requirements. The member banks of the Federal Reserve System had $6,800,000,000 of excess reserves by October.

There was also evidence that the demand for credit from the banks would develop. The amounts of money appropriated for the national defense program were on the levels of the peak of war demand in 1917. During the summer, Congress appropriated some $6,500,000,000 to be spent before June 1941. In the later months of 1940 Government expenditures were at the rate of some $750,000,000 to $880,000,000 a month. In no month did revenues provide for this expenditure and in one month the deficit was $803,000,000. At the end of October the gross debt of the United States Government was $44,137,000,000 and $5,810,000,000 of fully guaranteed obligations were outstanding also.

This deficit drew upon the funds of the banks in two ways. In the first place the member banks of the Federal Reserve System increased their holdings of securities during the year, thus providing funds for orders for armaments. In the second place, because of these demands the firms receiving orders turned to the banks for funds to supply their needs in constructing new plants and in increasing their production. At the end of the year commercial loans were increasing.

Because of the danger of inflation through the expansion of bank credit the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System applied to Congress for new powers to control the credit supply. The powers which they needed were primarily those of increasing reserve requirements and of limiting holdings of Government bonds. Also they wished to have revoked the powers of the Treasury and the President over the issue of paper currency and the value of the gold content of the dollar. This program was presented to Congress at the beginning of January 1941.

The increase in production of goods was accompanied by increases in exports in spite of the difficulties of shipping and the closing of continental markets through the British blockade. The value of these exports was surprisingly constant at a level of about $350,000,000 a month. The increase in exports to Great Britain was sufficiently large to counterbalance declines in exports to other parts of the world. The volume of imports was also well sustained. Here increases in trade with South America, Canada and Asia, other than Japan counterbalanced losses from Continental Europe. Thus, although the direction of foreign trade changed, its volume was not significantly disturbed.

Canada.

In Canada economic conditions followed a pattern similar to those of the United States. Business slumped in the beginning of the year and expanded again later. The index of industrial production (1926 = 100) dropped from 138 in December 1939 to 127 in March 1940 then rose to 153 in August. Price changes were even less than in the United States. The wholesale price index (1926 = 100) rose from 82 in December 1939 to 83 in September 1940. The cost of living index (1935-39 = 100) rose from 103.8 to 106.4 in the same period. The foreign exchange value of the currency did not remain stable. At the end of December, it had been 87.62 cents per dollar and in March it was 82.88 cents per dollar. At this time England established an official rate for the pound sterling and Canada did the same for her dollar. The rate chosen was 90.91 cents, a figure well above that of the free market. In the free market itself the rate subsequently rose but was still 86.32 cents at the end of October.

Latin America.

The South American countries were not as prosperous as their North American neighbors. The loss of their trade with Continental Europe was not as easily compensated. In Argentina for instance, although the export trade was only 3 per cent below that of the previous year in the first ten months in value, it was 21 per cent below in physical volume. In October even in value it was 45 per cent below last year's level. Exports of grain and fruits declined but that of meat increased. The production of petroleum increased 20 per cent in the first eight months of the year. In spite of these favorable factors the depression in the Argentine was severe. The grain markets were badly affected. At the end of 1939, grain prices had been high and the government ceased fixing minima for many products. In the fall of 1940 price fixing had to be reintroduced. The government was authorized to take over the entire wheat crop of 1940-41 at 54.7 cents a bushel. To alleviate distress among the industrial unemployed, the government introduced plans for new low cost housing projects.

Brazil similarly encountered difficulties of adjustment to the war basis. Exports of raw cotton declined to nearly half of what they had been a year before. The coffee market was unsettled. In the fall, however, the 14 coffee-producing States entered into an agreement establishing quotas for their exports to the United States. The new plan had a stabilizing effect on prices. A trade agreement with Argentina was negotiated.

The other raw material producing countries met the same problems. Cuban trade was dependent on its sales of sugar, and the sugar market was disrupted; Peru suffered from this same cause and also from the impossibility of selling its cotton. Chile, however, experienced much less trouble. Productive activity was well sustained and its foreign trade even increased.

The effect of the declines in trade showed themselves in the foreign exchange markets. In several of the smaller countries the exchange rates broke in spite of the official exchange controls; in Argentina, Brazil and Chile, they remained stable though imports had to be restricted. The United States made special efforts to help these countries stabilize their currencies. The Export-Import Bank made loans of two categories, first, to stabilize currencies directly, second, to organize and equip new industries. Stabilizing loans were made to Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Peru and Costa Rica; Industrial loans were made to Brazil for a steel plant and for an electric railway, to Chile for a hydroelectric plant and others to Nicaragua, Costa Rica, Panama, and to Paraguay to build roads. The amount of money involved in these loans was $650,000,000.

These loans by the Export-Import Bank provided financial relief to South America for relatively short periods. To provide more adequately for the future, a convention was drafted by delegates from the United States and the South American countries providing for the Inter-American Bank. This bank, to be capitalized at $100,000,000, will have broad powers to make long and short term loans, and to engage in any other financial activity which will be mutually beneficial to the trade of the countries involved. At the end of the year the Congress of the United States had not ratified the convention nor granted the charter though enough States had ratified to bring the Bank into being. (See also PAN-AMERICAN COOPERATION.)

The Orient.

In the Orient war conditions continued to produce economic deterioration. In Japan, in the first nine months, trade was on a higher level than last year, but in the autumn it declined. Japan, therefore, decided to discontinue trade statistics. A shortage of water in November led to a shortage of electricity which affected production seriously. The rice crop was the smallest in five years and exports of cotton cloth were 20 per cent less than last year. State controls over banking and business were extended and in shipping the Communications minister announced that there was to be a 'liquidation of liberalism.' Financial conditions remained relatively stable. Note circulation of the Bank of Japan expanded by nearly 30 per cent but prices rose by only 5 per cent. The gold reserves of the Bank remained as large as last year and the foreign exchange value of the yen was unchanged.

In China, conditions changed rapidly for the worse in 1940. Imports increased in value at a very rapid rate, partly in response to price changes, while exports remained at low levels. The consequence was an ever increasing pressure on the exchange market. The situation was aggravated by the unbalanced budget of the government. Funds were raised to a large extent from the commercial banks which covered the advances by increasing their note issues. Prices rose very rapidly. Wholesale prices at Shanghai, for instance, rose from 253 in August 1939 (1929 = 100) to 486 in August 1940. The yuan dropped in value from 7.49 cents in December 1939 to 5.08 cents in May 1940 and was 5.68 cents in October. These quotations conceal to some extent the real seriousness of the situation, for loans from the United States helped to support the market. The Export-Import Bank made one such loan in the spring and two in the fall totalling altogether $95,000,000. See also articles on the various countries involved and on BUSINESS; EUROPEAN WAR; INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCES; INTERNATIONAL LAW.

1939: World Economics

The War Crisis.

During 1939 the dominant factor underlying world economic conditions was the increasing political tension among the great powers which culminated in the outbreak of actual war in Europe in September. In the United States the tension caused a turning of economic activity into those channels which provide materials of war. Abroad, countries sought to secure sources of the raw materials of war or sufficient accumulations of foreign exchange to purchase such materials. To accomplish these objects, governments everywhere increased their expenditures, and the burden of indebtedness rose rapidly. The increases in government demands for goods and the creation of credit for their purchase led to increases of productive activity and decreases in unemployment. Financial structures in Europe began to show signs of strain before the end of 1939 though in the United States funds were still abundant. To protect themselves from the effects of inflation and to provide greater efficiency, governments assumed continually greater controls over economic enterprise. After war broke out in the belligerent countries only the barest remnant of free enterprise remained. In the Orient, the strains of war presented themselves in their more advanced stages. In spite of controls inflation was evident. South American economic life was disturbed but little and the year brought greater currency stability partly because of demands for raw materials from Europe. Throughout the year the struggle for markets led to methods of competition which tended to break down normal trade among nations, while the outbreak of war itself, with the embargoes and restrictions which accompanied it, almost completely severed such intercourse in many parts of the world. Neutral countries, particularly the American Commonwealths, attempted to strengthen commercial ties among themselves.

Expenditures for National Defense.

Economic conditions in the first nine months of 1939 in most European countries were centered about the problem of providing rapidly for greatly increased means of national defense. Even at the beginning of the year it was doubtful whether the Munich agreement would prevent war. The seizure of the remnants of Czechoslovakia, in April, dissolved what doubts remained and all energies were bent towards preparedness. The procuring of armaments on so large a scale entailed heavy government expenditures financed by borrowing. Thus even before war broke out the initial steps for large scale diversion of resources from private uses had been taken.

General.

In Great Britain expenditures for national defense in the fiscal year 1938-39 amounted to £400,000,000. In April the first budget estimate for 1939-40 was £580,000,000 but the figure was raised almost immediately to £630,000,000 and in July to £730,000,000. Even on the basis of £630,000,000 these expenditures would have been 43 per cent of total Government expenditures and 12 per cent of the total national income. The Government expected to raise fully £500,000,000 by borrowing. For France, the budget carried expenditures for the year 1939-40 of 40,885,000,000 francs, an amount equal to 49 per cent of all government expenditures and 18 per cent of the total national income. From January to June 1939, 23,000,000,000 francs had been borrowed and the national debt stood at 444,000,000,000 francs. For Germany, the Government budget is not made public. That expenditures for armaments are relatively high compared to France and England can be judged only from changes in the type of productive activity and in the government debt. At the end of March 1939 the funded debt of Germany amounted to 24,208,000,000 reichsmarks and the floating debt to 6,535,000,000 reichsmarks giving a total of 30,743,000,000 reichsmarks. At the end of March 1933 it had been 11,690,000,000 reichsmarks. Meantime, currency circulation has increased from 5,656,000,000 reichsmarks to 10,388,000,000 reichsmarks. Moreover, tax and customs receipts rose from 6,600,000,000 reichsmarks to 17,700,000,000 reichsmarks. Such a debt could only arise from tremendous expenditures on arms. Other countries of Europe also had heavy expenditures. The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics, for instance, provided for 40,885,000,000 rubles in their budget this year and Sweden, 272,000,000 krona. Even in the United States the need for means of defense became so evident that the budget for 1939-40 carried appropriations of $1,320,000,000, the largest amount for any peace time year.

Great Britain.

With expenditures of such magnitudes the financial structures of the various countries could not but be affected. At the Bank of England note circulation began to expand rapidly to meet the demands for payrolls. On Jan. 25, 1939, it had been £464,000,000 and on July 26 it was £511,000,000. Gold reserves underwent a series of changes tending to strengthen the Exchange Equalization Account. On Jan. 6, £200,000,000 was transferred to the Account from the Bank. On March 1, the gold stock of the Bank was revalued at current prices instead of legal parity and £5,500,000 were transferred back from the Account and on July 12 another £20,000,000 was added. As a result of these transactions the Bank had £279,000,000 when war broke out. In the banking department of the Bank discounts and advances declined and investments rose. At the clearing banks holdings of securities declined while loans and discounts dropped for the first three months of the year and then advanced steadily. Money rates in the market were low at the beginning of the year at .55 per cent for bankers' acceptances and .50 per cent for Treasury bills. At the time of the crisis in April, they jumped to 1.40 per cent and 1.36 per cent respectively. Thereafter, they did not return to their former low levels but were .79 per cent and .77 per cent in July. Security prices dropped during the early months of the year, stiffened after the crisis but declined again as tension increased in August. The price of consols declined continuously with yields of 3.46 per cent in January and 3.96 per cent in July. New capital issues exclusive of Government issues declined in volume. Wholesale commodity prices were practically stationary with an index (1930 = 100) of 97 in January and 98 in August.

France.

In France, financial changes progressed more rapidly. Note circulation of the Bank of France rose from 109,378,000,000 francs in January to 123,239,000,000 francs in July. Gold holdings were strengthened by transfers of 5,000,000,000 francs on April 20 and again on Aug. 3. Deposits declined during the April crisis but rose again thereafter. Advances to the Government and bills discounted showed no marked trends. At commercial banks bills increased steadily, while deposits rose until May, but declined somewhat in June and July. Money rates in the open market were much lower than in 1938 at 1.94 per cent in January and 1.88 per cent in July. Security prices moved erratically but remained well above their level in 1938. New capital issues were a little higher than in the previous year. Commodity prices declined from an index of 689 (1913 = 100) in January to 674 in August.

Germany.

In Germany, the note issues of the Reichsbank expanded more rapidly than note issues in either France or England. At the end of January, they were 7,816,000,000 reichsmarks and on July 31 they were 8,989,000,000 reichsmarks. Since reserves remained practically constant, the increases were covered by increased holdings of securities, and holdings of Treasury bills expanded also. Commercial bank discounts increased steadily as did deposits. Money rates declined from 2.88 per cent in January to 2.75 per cent in July. Security prices declined and new capital issues remained at last year's levels.

Other Countries.

In the countries that were later neutral similar tendencies were visible. Everywhere note issues expanded and bank deposits tended to rise. Interest rates varied from country to country. In Sweden and Italy, rates were constant at 2.50 per cent and 5.25 per cent respectively. Holland and Belgium both suffered severely at the time of the crisis in April. In Belgium, the open market rate rose from 1.98 per cent in February to 4.28 per cent in April, and in Holland, from .19 per cent to 1.28 per cent. Later those rates declined again. In the United States note issues expanded from $6,839,000,000 in January to $7,902,000,000 in July; gold reserves (see below) increased from $14,565,000,000 to $16,227,000,000. Commercial bank deposits rose from $21,231,000,000 to $22,705,000,000. Interest rates remained at low levels throughout the period except for a slight tightening of rates on Treasury issues at the crisis. Security prices declined in the early months of the year and dropped precipitously at the crisis. During the remainder of the period they rose again slowly. New capital issues were in small volume except for Federal Government issues.

Industrial Comparisons.

Great Britain.

The effects of the preparations for war showed themselves also in productive activity. In Great Britain, the general index of production (1930 = 100) which stood at 126 in December 1938 rose to 133 in June 1939. For many lines of goods which are closely associated with defense, production was practically at capacity in June. Thus the steel industry was near its effective capacity of 14,700,000 tons per annum and the engineering industry was having to lengthen delivery dates. A shortage of labor was developing in this industry and in the wool trade it became necessary to hold up civil orders. The coal industry could still expand but it was doubtful that there would be any export surplus in the winter when seasonal demands became high. Although wage rates, and hence costs, had not yet risen, total payments to labor increased because of increased employment, the index for which (1935 = 100) rose from 110 in January to 115 in June. The increase in purchasing power increased demands for consumption goods, so that production in these lines, too, was heavy.

France.

In France, similar tendencies existed. The general index of production (1928 = 100) increased from 86 at the end of December 1938 to 100 in June 1939. War industries again were most favored but other industries such as the export industries and automobile production received benefits. The low level of French prices compared to world prices was a factor in stimulating non-war demand. Unemployment decreased and a shortage of skilled workers developed. It is difficult to trace the extent of stimulation of the consumption goods industries in general but in the building industry expansion was marked.

Germany.

In Germany, productive activity had reached a high level last year but the general index (1929 = 100) rose further from 129 in December 1938 to 135 in July 1939. Here the labor shortage was sufficient to prevent the continued expansion of both armaments and consumption goods and consumption goods were sacrificed. The index for investment goods (chiefly armaments) increased from 131 in January to 147 in July, while that for consumption goods dropped from 124 to 117 in June but rose to 120 in July. Thus in spite of the rigid control of prices the population must be suffering from decreases in actual standard of living.

Other Countries.

In other European countries productive activity followed a similar course. The general index (1929 = 100) rose from January to June, for Belgium, from 74 to 81; for Denmark, from 138 to 146; for Norway, from 125 to 139; for Poland, from 118 to 127; for Sweden, from 147 to 156. In America, the situation was somewhat different. In Canada, production followed the same course as abroad with an index which increased from 90 to 98. In the United States, the production index dropped from 86 in January to 77 in May. Only in summer did activity begin to advance. To be sure, war orders from abroad did not affect American markets until summer and the domestic armament program was later in getting under way but expenditures for relief had remained high. The number of unemployed remained alarmingly large.

Trade Comparisons.

Foreign trade, like production, tended to increase. Imports were necessary to build up stocks of goods against the time of war while exports were necessary to supply exchange. For Great Britain, the index of imports (1935 = 100) for the first two quarters of the year were 108 and 113 respectively compared to 111 and 104 last year and for exports 102 and 101 compared to 100 and 94. For France, imports amounted to 24,766,000,000 francs compared with 23,264,000,000 francs last year while exports were 18,040,000,000 francs compared to 13,964,000,000 francs a year before. For Germany (including Austria) on the other hand trade declined, for imports from 2,883,000,000 reichsmarks to 2,734,000,000 reichsmarks and exports from 2,796,000,000 reichsmarks to 2,793,000,000 reichsmarks, leaving an adverse balance of trade. For the United States, the export trade declined while the import trade increased, but an excess of exports of some $50,000,000 a month still continued.

Gold Movements.

Partly because of the balance of trade but chiefly because of the political tension, gold was exported to the United States in amounts even greater than during 1938. In April alone $606,000,000 net were imported and in the months from then until October the figure never fell below $250,000,000 a month. By far the larger portion of this gold came from the United Kingdom, but substantial amounts were sent from Belgium, the Netherlands, Switzerland and Canada. Almost none came from France. In fact throughout the first seven months of 1939 France gained gold in considerable quantities. The quantities of gold exported from the United Kingdom and Canada are partly fictitious. These countries were simply intermediaries between continental countries and the United States. Of the gold exported from England, a large portion had come in turn from Belgium, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the British Dominions, while most of the gold from Canada came originally from England. In spite of the magnitude of these movements exchange rates remained stable chiefly because of the support of Exchange Equalization Funds.

Aspects of the War Crisis.

As the necessity for mobilizing national resources became more apparent and as mounting public debts began to suggest the possibility of inflation, governments assumed more and more control of economic organization.

Germany.

In Germany the powers of the Government were already tremendous, but they were further increased this year. Dr. Schacht, who had accomplished so much for the Reich financially but who stood firmly against inflation, was relieved of the presidency of the Reichsbank and replaced by Dr. Funk, Minister of Economics, who was willing to assure conformity of financial policy to general governmental policies at all costs. He immediately issued new currency in the form of tax certificates which Government agencies were allowed to use in payment of 40 per cent of their purchases. Recipients of these certificates were allowed to use them again for 40 per cent of their costs. The certificates carried a reduction in taxes if they were used in their payment after from six to eighteen months. Thus the Government began to anticipate its income and the straight road to inflation was opened. A billion marks of this kind were issued by June. That the danger of inflation was a very real one was shown by the new decrees regulating prices which were issued in April. Prices had been controlled for some time but the new orders were much more stringent. The low of October 1936 had provided for rises in prices only when changes in costs justified them; under the new plan, the Price Commissioner was given dictatorial powers. Industries might include in costs only standard wage payments fixed by the commissioner. Thus the commissioner by properly fixing costs and final prices might render unprofitable any industry which was unwanted. This decree completes the breakdown of the principle of price as an adjuster of demand and supply. A further step in government control was the consolidation of the Reichsbank in the Government. Shareholders were forced to transfer their stock into other securities. German citizens had to accept Government bonds but foreign stockholders received shares in the Gold Discount Bank. For foreigners this meant little economic loss but to the Reichsbank it meant complete freedom from outside controls. Immediately thereafter the Bank ceased publishing figures for the gold reserve and the note circulation was freed from even nominal limitation.

France.

In France, the loss of economic freedom began seriously only in November 1938 and was by no means in the same category with Germany. Although the Government issued decrees concerning economic matters these decrees had as their purpose primarily the restoration of monetary stability within a framework of monetary freedom. With regard to labor, the November decrees allowed greater conformity to freedom of contract. In March and April, a new series of decrees brought a definite movement towards a controlled war economy. The decrees were directed towards three ends: an effective distribution of the labor force, a limitation upon consumption, and a limitation upon the creation of money. Employers' freedom of engagement was limited so as to direct labor towards industries important for defense; the normal week was increased to 45 hours with possibility of a 60 hour week, compensated by overtime pay. In defense industries, taxes were increased. State orders were given priority over private orders with all manufacturers, and industries working on State contracts were forbidden to compete for labor. The central wheat office was reorganized and an attempt was made to induce people to return to the land.

Great Britain.

In Great Britain, too, the Government began to take steps early in the spring to mold the economy to war needs. To some extent this was accomplished by means of subsidies. Shipping subsidies helped to foster a merchant marine and subsidies for increasing acreage under cultivation, for building up reserves of fertilizers, seeds, farm machinery, and so forth, provided for increased agricultural production. In April, the formation of a Ministry of Supply was announced. Its powers were to include the right to secure priority of Government orders, the right to require business firms to produce for the State and even to alter their plant to do so. Companies' books were made subject to government inspection to determine fair prices. This program was not put into effect immediately; the ministry announced that compulsion would not be used as long as there was sufficient voluntary compliance.

International Trade.

In the field of international trade, governments continued to foster exports artificially, Germany extended the use of Aski marks and of clearing agreements. In April, added financial facilities were given to German exporters. The Reichsbank gave reduced discount rates and longer currency for export bills; new methods of insuring against exchange risks were provided and the German stamp duty on bills drawn in foreign currencies was suppressed. To protect itself against subsidized goods, the United States imposed a 25 per cent duty on dutiable goods imported from Germany, and in July imposed a similar duty on Italian goods. To meet the competition for foreign markets both Great Britain and the United States resorted to subsidizing trade. In both countries, quasi-government banks existed to make loans for foreign trade. In 1939, the funds available for these institutions were increased and their business was extended. The Export Credit Guarantee Department of the United Kingdom made loans to New Zealand to finance imports from Great Britain and to the Chinese government to help stabilize its currency. The Export-Import Bank of the United States made loans to finance imports from the United States to Paraguay, Poland, Portugal, the Argentine, China, Brazil and Finland. The United States Treasury made a direct loan to Brazil to stabilize its currency and it added this year a direct subsidy on the export of cotton. France made a beginning in this field with a large loan to Poland for electrification schemes to be repaid through additional Polish exports to France and liberalized the terms of her clearing agreements with Rumania and Jugoslavia. Finally, the governments of the United States and Great Britain resorted to direct barter of stocks of surplus commodities, exchanging 600,000 bales of cotton for 80,000 tons of rubber. It was understood that these commodities would be used for emergency war stocks only. All of these schemes show the increasing difficulties of carrying on foreign trade when markets tend to be monopolized by nations having clearing agreements and the lengths to which such competition drives the exporting nations.

Such were economic conditions in the western world when war actually broke out. The war itself served to complete the difficulties of world trade. The danger to commerce all over the world and, of course, especially in the North and Baltic seas virtually closed many countries to trade, and embargoes intensified the difficulties. Embargoes were placed not only by belligerents against each other but by governments on their citizens to prevent the loss of essential products. The conduct of the war proved to be peculiar. The expected air attacks did not take place, and real warfare on the western front had not developed at the end of the year. Hence the demand for explosives and ammunition was much less than expected, while that for aircraft and shipping much larger.

Government-controlled War Economies.

The first effect of war in the belligerent countries was the extension of controls over the economic life of the countries so that little freedom existed. In Germany, control had been so complete before the war that little extension was necessary. In Great Britain, measures had been prepared and their application took place almost at once. First to be enforced were financial restrictions. The Exchange Equalization Account ceased selling gold and all the gold reserve of the Bank of England was transferred to the Account. At the same time, the fiduciary issue of the bank was raised to £580,000,000. Foreign exchange could be obtained only through the Bank of England. Although the acceptance houses and merchant bankers, the usual channels for supplying exchange, still had direct access to the bank, the Clearing Banks were designated as official agents. All residents of Great Britain, whether citizens or not, were required to register their holdings of foreign exchange and of foreign securities. Thereafter, they could transfer these assets to other residents of Great Britain under license but not to outsiders except under the most exceptional circumstances. In this manner, the export of capital was prevented. The security markets also came under close supervision. Minimum prices were fixed for all securities. The price chosen was that at the close of the market on Aug. 23. Trading for the Account was discontinued for the duration of the war. New capital issues could be floated only subject to regulation. Thus was financial control shifted to the Exchequer. It is doubtful whether the London market can ever return to its former organization. The merchant bankers and acceptance houses are losing their business in exchange and in securities. Besides, they were heavily loaded with acceptance credits, for instance under the Standstill agreements with Germany, which probably never will be repaid. Although the Bank of England offered temporary loans against such collateral at a penalty rate of 6 per cent ultimate losses will fall on the private bankers.

Control was not confined to finance. The Ministry of Supply began to assume its full functions. All essential supplies had to be ordered and distributed under its supervision. Commodity prices were fixed at the level prevailing on August first subject to certain adjustments for changes in costs, upon approval of the Government. The Government undertook to regulate transportation and shipping. Thus, of the old order of free enterprise very little remained.

In France, similar conditions prevailed. The Bank of France took over the regulation of foreign exchange and security issues. Commodity prices were fixed at September levels. Limits were set to increases in wages and profits. Embargoes were placed on the export of essential products. Taxes were increased. Government by decree was extended. Even in the United States the Government increased its power. At first, an embargo was placed on all exports of arms and implements of war. Later, this Embargo Act was repealed but American ships were forbidden to enter the combat areas and sales to belligerent countries were allowed only under the 'cash and carry' system. Moreover, the President declared that a situation of limited emergency existed, thus conferring unusual powers upon the chief executive.

Great Britain.

Along with the breakdown of economic freedom went extensions of the economic tendencies which developed during this period of increasing tension. In Great Britain, the immediate effect of the outbreak of war was a tightening of money rates of even greater magnitude than had occurred in April. The Bank rate was raised to 4 per cent on Aug. 26. Open market rates rose in sympathy. Bankers' Acceptances had been discounted at .79 per cent in July but in September the rate averaged 3.51 per cent. Rates on Treasury bills rose from .77 per cent to 3.23 per cent and day-to-day from .77 per cent to 2.72 per cent. These rates were not maintained for a long period. On Sept. 28, bank rates dropped to 3 per cent and on Oct. 26 to 2 per cent. The rate on Bankers' Acceptances was 1.88 per cent, at the end of October, that for Treasury bills 1.77 per cent, and day-to-day money 1.71 per cent. Although these rates were not as low as those prevailing in the spring, they were exceedingly low for a war period. Meantime, the debt of the government mounted. The floating debt had been £1,138,000,000 on Aug. 26; it became £1,311,000,000 on Oct. 28. Note issues of the Bank of England expanded. At the end of July, they had amounted to £510,000,000, at the end of September to £542,000,000, but at the beginning of November they had declined again to £527,000,000. Wholesale prices of foods in spite of the controls, rose from an index of 90 (1930 = 100) in August to 109 in October. Prices of industrial products rose from 102 in August to 107 in September (the October figure is not yet available). Cost of living (1914 = 100) jumped similarly from 155 in August to 165 in October. No index for production for the period after the beginning of the war is available. That productive activity was seriously dislocated is evident from the unemployment figures. Between Aug. 14 and Sept. 11, the number of unemployed increased by 98,000, and between Sept. 11 and Oct. 16, by another 101,000, in spite of the fact that large numbers of men previously employed were called to the colors. The decreases in employment came primarily in the luxury trades and were chiefly among women. Increases came in such industries as the metal trades, textiles, coal mining, tailoring, dress-making, and fishing. Foreign trade was very seriously curtailed. Imports in September were 33 per cent lower than in September 1938, while exports declined by 41 per cent. The foreign exchange rate was allowed to decline with only enough support from the Exchange Control to maintain an orderly market. Before war broke out, it had been $4.68. In the last week of September, it was $3.75. Thereafter it rallied somewhat, but by the first week in December it was $3.88.

France.

In France, the favorable condition of the money market made it unnecessary to raise the discount rate of the Bank of France when war broke out. However, the private discount rate did rise from 1.95 per cent in August to 2.70 per cent in September. At the Bank of France, Government borrowing showed its effects. Direct advances to the Government rose from 20,577,000,000 francs at the end of August to 25,473,000,000 francs at the end of October. The Bank's holdings of commercial bills also increased. 'Other' domestic bills which were 5,000,000,000 francs at the end of July rose to 15,009,000,000 francs at the end of August, and 14,830,000,000 francs at the end of September. After the initial disruption of the markets passed the amount of these discounts returned to 8,298,000,000 francs. The note circulation increased from 123,239,000,000 francs at the end of July to 144,379,000,000 francs at the end of October. Deposits of both the Government and private individuals declined. Figures for production and trade since the war are not available. Shortages of labor in many fields were reported, however. The proportion of men called to the colors was much higher than in Great Britain and the relative number of unemployed was smaller. In the foreign exchange market, the franc weakened progressively as did the pound. Early in December, it was 2.22 cents.

Germany.

In Germany, the outbreak of war caused little disturbance since the country was already on a war footing. Neither the Reichsbank rate nor private interest rates changed. Note issues of the Reichsbank rose at the end of August from 8,989,000,000 to 10,907,000,000 reichsmarks, but declined a little in October. Holdings of Treasury bills and securities eligible for coverage for the note issue also increased. The new type of currency introduced in the spring proved to be a failure after war broke out and was discontinued after market value fell to 94 per cent of face value. Prices of commodities have fallen officially from 107.1 (1913 = 100) in August to 106.9. Actually there were many illicit increases in prices, a fact to which the number of fines paid by shopkeepers for raising prices gave evidence. In production, there developed an acute shortage of skilled workers. Apprentices were assigned to skilled occupations according to the importance of the industry in the prosecution of war. A decree ordered forced labor for all women between the ages of 15 and 70 years. Production of unessentials, particularly those requiring imported materials, was severely curtailed. Soap and textile manufacture were especially affected. The drive to expand exports was pressed especially upon Scandinavian countries. The reports of the German Dutch Clearing Account show that Germany has maintained her exports to Holland but that imports have decreased. A similar fall in the Clearing deficit with Switzerland is expected. This improvement in the balance of trade is undoubtedly the result of the British blockade which restricts re-exports from neutrals to Germany.

Other European Countries.

The neutral countries by no means escaped the problems of war adjustments. Sweden, for instance, is dependent on shipping for her foreign trade and was thus especially affected by the embargoes. Her trade except with Germany has decreased. Although supplies of foodstuffs were ample, other essentials were lacking. A shortage of gasoline led to a prohibition of the use of private cars. At the Bank of Sweden, gold reserves declined as well as reserves of foreign assets, while note issues rose. The exchange rate weakened progressively. In Holland and Belgium, the imminence of war made conditions even more difficult. In Holland, for instance, the private discount rate rose from .51 per cent in July to 2.94 per cent in September, while month money rose from .75 per cent to 3.66 per cent. Even in October the rates were still 1.90 per cent and 2.24 per cent respectively. In both countries, gold and foreign exchange holdings declined and note issues expanded. Foreign exchange rates weakened especially at the end of the year.

United States.

In the United States, the war produced conditions which were favorable to economic activity. It is true that the market for government securities did respond unfavorably but money rates for commercial loans in the open market remained unchanged. Issues of Federal Reserve Notes increased but little and gold reserves continued to expand. In other phases of economic life that expansion of the summer continued at an accelerated pace. Production increased at an extraordinary rate. The index of production (1923-25 = 100 adjusted) rose from 103 in August to 120 in October. The general index of wholesale prices (1926 = 100) rose from 75 in August to 79 in October, while the prices of basic commodities rose by 33 per cent. Although the prices of agricultural products were most responsive at first, later they declined again, while prices of industrial and imported basic commodities continued to rise. There developed almost a shortage of railroad facilities. In September and October, foreign trade expanded somewhat more than seasonally. Security prices, too, rose in these months. Later, however, there developed a certain hesitancy in business. Although business activity continued to expand, security prices did not continue to rise. New capital issues almost ceased except for government issues. New construction was at a low level. All of the facts support the conclusion that at this period business was very uncertain of the future course of production. The warfare was of an unexpected variety requiring much less in the way of armaments than was expected originally. Trade with many countries was cut off and the possibility of increasing trade with South America had not been fully explored. As a result, business men were unwilling to involve themselves in future commitments.

South America.

In South America, the problems of oncoming war had been more remote in the early part of the year. In the early months in some countries there was a recession similar to that in the United States. In Chile, the disastrous earthquake in January destroyed thirty cities and towns. The rebuilding of these towns was expected to take several years. In Brazil, the weakening of the currency caused advances in prices which disturbed business. In the Argentine, there was a bumper wheat crop but the corn crop was very small. Before summer, foreign trade had expanded. Exports of wheat to France and England helped the trade of the Argentine, while cotton exports from Brazil chiefly to Germany and Japan were high. The expansion of the export trade with a relatively stationary import trade in many countries caused the foreign exchanges to improve. For Brazil, the establishment of the Exchange Equalization Fund with the help of American loans in March served as a stabilizing influence. The official rate for the milreis had been allowed to drop from 8.72 cents to 5.84 cents in December 1938. In June 1939, it was raised to 6.06 cents. In the free market, the rate declined to 5.1038 cents in June and then remained relatively stable for the rest of the year. In Colombia, the exchange rate rose a little in March and remained high for the rest of the year. For Cuba and Chile, the rate was very stable. In Mexico, the rate declined in the summer after the United States Treasury reduced its buying price for foreign silver. In the Argentine, the rate remained stable until September. The outbreak of the war had at first a stimulating effect in most South American countries. The rises in agricultural prices served to alter favorably their balance of foreign trade. Retail trade at home expanded rapidly under the impetus of the new prices. However, by October, the sudden spurt in activity receded as it became evident that foreign trade would not benefit immediately by the war. Brazil was injured by her loss of German markets. Cuba had enjoyed a brief boom in sugar, while the retail demand in the United States had been high. Conditions in Mexico and Chile remained relatively stable. Argentina suffered difficulties with the exchanges induced in part by the decline of sterling. The rate dropped from 31.1 cents in August to 29.8 cents in October. In Mexico, on the other hand, the rate rose. On the whole, the final effects of war on South America could not be evaluated at the end of the year. The immediate effect was to strengthen all political relations among the several Latin American countries and with the United States. From these political relations may come strengthened commercial relations. The United States is being very cooperative in the matter of extending credits through the Export-Import Bank and in the extension of the system of reciprocal trade agreements. An agreement with Ecuador was completed this year and one with the Argentine is to be negotiated shortly.

Japan.

In the Orient, the strains of their own war were so great as to obliterate almost entirely the signs of the war in Europe. In Japan, the outstanding feature has been the increase in inflation. Note issues of the Bank of Japan reached a peak of 2,806,000,000 yen at the end of October, an increase of 624,000,000 yen in a year. The wholesale commodity price index (October 1900 = 100) rose from 255 in December 1938 to 288 in September 1939. Retail prices in Tokyo rose 13 per cent in the year. The government tried to stem the tide of rising prices by further controls and limitations upon prices and profits. A failure of the rice crop forced the government to raise its price and added further to the decline in the standard of living. Meantime, production in many lines was pushed so far that shortages of labor became apparent. Silk production was 10 per cent greater than last year. Because of the restrictions on the importation of textiles, home consumption of silk was 26 per cent greater than last year. Foreign trade this year expanded greatly. For the first ten months of the year, exports amounted to 3,071,000,000 yen, an increase of 789,000,000 yen over last year, while imports amounted to 2,566,000,000 yen, an increase of only 226,000,000 yen. The relative increase in exports relieved the strain on the foreign exchanges and allowed the Bank of Japan to keep its gold reserve intact. In the fall, the foreign exchange did break. It had been tied to sterling and when sterling declined it declined also from 27.28 cents in July to 23.51 cents in October. It was later stabilized by tieing it to the value of the dollar. Prospects of further difficulties next year arose when the United States denounced its commercial treaty in July to take effect in January 1940.

China.

In China, conditions have been even worse. Note issues of the Central Bank of China, the Bank of China and Bank of Communications, in June (only figure available this year) were 2,301,000,000 yuan compared with 1,465,000,000 yuan in June 1938. Interest rates in Shanghai rose to 6.52 per cent from 4.22 per cent in December 1938. The index of wholesale prices (1929 = 100) stood in September at 304 compared to 159 at the end of last year, and the index of the cost of living rose from 134 to 224 in the same period. A foreign trade balance did not assist the foreign exchange market. Imports this year increased very considerably over last year, while exports decreased. Both Great Britain and the United States extended loans to help stabilize the exchange rate. It is too early to judge the effectiveness of the attempts. The rate had been 15.89 cents per yuan at Shanghai in January. It declined to 6.70 cents in September, but recovered to 7.64 cents in October. See also INTERNATIONAL BANKING AND FINANCE; INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCES.